Some Thoughts on the Carter Report

Publication
The Empire Club of Canada Addresses (Toronto, Canada), 16 Mar 1967, p. 277-305
Description
Speaker
Fleming, The Hon. Donald M., Speaker
Media Type
Text
Item Type
Speeches
Description
The Carter Report. A Royal Commission to conduct a complete study of the federal tax system and structure, appointed in the Spring of 1962 by the Minister of Finance. The speaker's views: a preliminary review and assessment of the report, necessarily confined to some broad considerations and certain of its highlights. Some background on the Commission and why it was appointed. The terms of reference given to the Commission by the government. The members of the Commission. The staff of expert advisers. A tribute from the speaker to all members of the Commission. The Commission's revolutionary report. The extreme nature of the changes recommended as the greatest obstacle to public and parliamentary acceptance. A discussion of the revolutionary nature of the report. The need for the public to understand what the introduction of a radically new system of taxation will involve. The difficulties which would be faced by the government and the public service in introducing the new tax system. The time required to implement such change. What the recommendations would mean in terms of tax revenue. The Commission's indictment of the present tax system. A more detailed look at some specific recommendations under the following headings: Capital Gains; Employment and Other Income; Expense Accounts; Estates—Gifts and Bequests; Corporations; Banks; Mines and Petroleum Industries; Life Insurance; Charities; Sales Tax; Provinces and Municipalities; Administration; Simplification of Forms and Procedures; Foreign Capital; Balance of Payments; Stabilization Policies; Severability; Conclusion. The speaker's hope that his observations will encourage members of the audience to study "this very valuable, stimulating, challenging and most controversial report. Its importance justifies our attentive study; its contents will fully repay it."
Date of Original
16 Mar 1967
Subject(s)
Language of Item
English
Copyright Statement
The speeches are free of charge but please note that the Empire Club of Canada retains copyright. Neither the speeches themselves nor any part of their content may be used for any purpose other than personal interest or research without the explicit permission of the Empire Club of Canada.

Views and Opinions Expressed Disclaimer: The views and opinions expressed by the speakers or panelists are those of the speakers or panelists and do not necessarily reflect or represent the official views and opinions, policy or position held by The Empire Club of Canada.
Contact
Empire Club of Canada
Email:info@empireclub.org
Website:
Agency street/mail address:

Fairmont Royal York Hotel

100 Front Street West, Floor H

Toronto, ON, M5J 1E3

Full Text
MARCH 16, 1967
Some Thoughts On The Carter Report
AN ADDRESS BY: The Hon. Donald M. Fleming, P.C., Q.C., FORMER MINISTER OF FINANCE
CHAIRMAN, The First Vice-President, Graham M. Gore

MR. GORE:

This is an unusual day. In the first place, you are subjected to a substitute chairman, because our president is away from Toronto for a few days. In the second place, your speaker will not be "introduced" but "presented". It would not be proper for your chairman to introduce our speaker to members who know him well. He is a fellow member of our club, a former member of the executive committee, and has addressed us on a number of occasions. In the past he has provided us with much valuable information, particularly in the area of finance. I cannot vouch that many members have made great fortunes on the information which he provided, but it is usually interesting to hear about matters of finance from one who knows the facts. We are certain that the government will take a great portion of the national income because payment must be made for all the services which it provides, and government money is obtained from "taxes". In the most recent annual report of a company on which our speaker serves as a member of the Board of Directors, there is the following statement:

"Few Canadians realize that government expenditures on social security in Canada in 1965 already constitute about the same percentage of national income as in such 'welfare states' as New Zealand and the United Kingdom and that this ratio is about 50% higher than that which exists in the United States, a far wealthier nation than Canada."

The members of our club are very fortunate today in having a speaker who has given so much of his skill, energy and talents in such fields as law, finance, government, church, business, education, international affairs and good works.

In view of the recent presentation of the voluminous report of the commission on taxation and in view of the fact that our speaker was a member of the government when the decision was made to establish a commission to study the field of taxation, and in view of the fact that one so knowledgeable and experienced in this field is prepared to tell us about the report, I am very honoured to present a great Canadian whom I have been privileged to call "friend" for many years, the Hon. Donald M. Fleming, P.c., Q.C., B.A., LL.B., D.C.L., to address us on the topic -

"Some Thoughts on the Carter Report".

MR. FLEMING:

It was said by Alexander Pope that "Fools rush in where angels fear to tread." It may not be the role of prudence to attempt anything approaching a com prehensive commentary on the Carter Report just twenty days after its publication. Against my natural caution however, I have yielded to the persuasion of our President. I can assure you that I have developed a very healthy respect for his powers of persuasion, not to mention temptation. He has convinced me that I owe a responsibility to the Canadian public to break a self-imposed silence and to comment even at this early stage on the report of the Royal Commission on Taxation. I was Minister of Finance when in the spring of 1962 the government of the day announced its intention to appoint a Royal Commission to conduct a complete study of the federal tax system and structure. As a member of that government I participated in the selection of the members of the Commission and in the determination of the terms of reference contained in the Order-in-Council, dated September 25, 1962. I take my full share of responsibility for the establishment of the Commission.

I have deliberately chosen as my subject "Some Thoughts on the Carter Report" to emphasize that my treatment of the report cannot pretend to be complete. Its sheer size, with its six thousand pages of condensed material, following four years of patient study, would forbid any serious pretence of complete study in twenty days of all its findings and recommendations. Similarly, the physical proportions of the report and the scope of the Commission's studies preclude any attempt at exhaustive treatment in the space of one address. Rather the report would afford material for an extended series of lectures. Today, therefore, in the few minutes at my disposal I cannot hope to offer you more than a preliminary review and assessment of the report, necessarily confined to some broad considerations and certain of its highlights. The views I express are mine alone.

The Commission was appointed for the first place because the government was convinced of the need for a comprehensive and critical study of the entire structure and system of federal taxation in Canada. The annual budget process, with its intensive review of fiscal needs and tax proposals may suffice for normal current purposes, but something much more far-reaching had, in the opinion of the government, become desirable. Obviously the highly competent but heavily burdened officers of the Department of Finance and the Department of National Revenue were unable to undertake such a duty. Sheer physical considerations precluded it, apart altogether from the fact that a fresh approach was considered by some to be desirable. Furthermore, the role of permanent government advisers is different from that of a royal commission. Politics being the art of the possible, senior government advisers are often more disposed to give greater weight to practical considerations than are royal commissions, and their approach is consequently often more cautious.

The terms of reference given to the Commission by the government were extremely broad. It is necessary to quote them in order to appreciate the breadth of the report: -

"to inquire into and report upon the incidence and effects of taxation imposed by Parliament, including any changes made during the currency of the inquiry, upon the operation of the national economy, the conduct of business, the organization of industry and the positions of individuals; and to make recommendations for improvements in the tax laws and their administration that may be consistent with the maintenance of a sufficient flow of revenue; and without restricting the generality of the foregoing, the Commission shall consider and report upon:

(a) the distribution of burdens among taxpayers resulting from existing rates, exemptions, reliefs and allowances provided in the personal and corporation income taxes, estate taxes and sales and excise taxes, taking into account also the jurisdiction and practices of the provinces and municipalities;
(b) the effects of the tax system on employment, living standards, savings and investment, industrial productivity, and economic stability and growth;
(c) provisions in existing laws which may have given rise over the years to anomalies or inequities or which may require action to close loopholes which permit the use of devices to avoid fair taxation;
(d) the effects of the income, sales and excise taxes and estate duties on income and investment flows which effect the balance of international payments and economic relations with other countries;
(e) the means whereby the tax laws can best be formulated to encourage Canadian ownership of Canadian industry without discouraging the flow of investment funds into Canada;
(f) the changes that may be made to achieve greater clarity, simplicity and effectiveness in the tax laws or their administrations; and
(g) such other related matters as the Commissioners consider pertinent or relevant to the specific or general scope of the inquiry."

Sometimes the appointment of a royal commission is looked upon as the solution of a problem. I warned in 1962 that the appointment of the Royal Commission might lead to the need not for fewer, but for more difficult decisions. I may not have been wrong.

The members of the Commission were chosen with great care. I believe we were extremely fortunate in enlisting the willing services of such outstanding persons as constituted the Commission. Mr. Kenneth Carter is an eminent leader in the accountancy profession in Canada. He is a man with the highest sense of public responsibility. Mr. Harvey Perry is a recognized expert in the tax field with long experience, in succession with the Department of Finance, The Canadian Tax Foundation, The Canadian Bankers Association. Mr. A. Emile Beauvais is another recognized leader in the accountancy profession and a leading authority in the tax field. Mr. Donald Grant, with a distinguished legal background, is President of The Nova Scotia Trust Company. Mrs. S. M. Milne is both a business-woman and housewife. She has engaged in accounting and is Chairman of Finance for the National Council of Women. Col. Charles Walls, after being engaged in insurance in Western Canada, pursued a career in agriculture and was manager of The British Columbia Federation of Agriculture until recently. It would have been difficult to assemble a more competent or better balanced Royal Commission to undertake a comprehensive review of the federal tax structure. Expert knowledge was blended with broad experience and representative qualifications.

No partisan considerations entered into the selection of the members of the Commission. The Chairman is known to have no party affiliation or leaning. No member of the Commission was asked to arrive at any predetermined conclusion. The Commission was literally entrusted with its task. The independence of judgment of every member was respected.

The Commission wisely surrounded itself with a highly competent staff of expert advisers. They covered all of the related fields-law, economics, accountancy. The organiza tion of the enormous task was in itself a remarkable achievement

There is always a tendency to identify a royal commission with the chairman-in particular, to identify its report with his name. Perhaps this tendency serves to concentrate atten tion unduly on one person. Any serious approach to the Carter Report must take due account of the high qualifications of all members of the Commission.

Two members of the Commission, Mr. Beauvais and Mr. Grant, have written vigorous minority reports, which will command very wide respect.

Regardless of anyone's views either on particular aspects of the report or on broader grounds, I wish to pay my tribute to all members of the Commission for the serious, respon sible, courageous and painstaking effort which they have devoted to an undertaking of the highest national importance. The task was long and arduous. The Commission shirked no part of it. It spared no effort. For sheer thoroughness and comprehensiveness I doubt if any royal commission has ever surpassed the Carter Commission. Even on the part of those who differ from its recommendations in whole or in part, I hope it is not too much to expect that we will give full recognition to the notable public service which the six members of the Commission have rendered.

The Commission has written a report which can fairly be described as revolutionary. The extreme nature of the changes recommended by the Commission will probably be the greatest obstacle to public and parliamentary acceptance thereof. The Commission has recognized that some of its recommendations will be more palatable and acceptable to the public than others. It has sought therefore to put forward its proposals as a package. On page 2 of Volume 1 of the report the Commission has said,

"Great damage could be done by the espousal of all the popular measures recommended and rejection of the others-without appreciating that the politically attractive changes are only feasible as part of an integrated programme".

Unless governments and parliaments have changed greatly and unless popular taste has been transformed, this plea of Commission is likely to fall on deaf ears. For my own part let me say briefly at this stage that I shall have praise for some elements in the report, and shall respectfully disagree with others, in whole or in part. I simply do not believe that the Commission can realistically hope to see this report considered only as a complete package, to be approached on a take-it-or-leave-it basis.

I said that the report is of a revolutionary nature. There have been legislative changes in our tax system in the past that have been far-reaching in their effects often beyond the thought of those responsible for them. The introduction of the income tax by Sir Thomas White in 1917 was regarded as most revolutionary at the time. In the view of some the Estate Tax Act which I introduced in 1958, replacing the old Dominion Succession Duty, may have been an important step in the development of our federal tax system. But these and many others which could be cited from history, cannot compare with the proposals of the Carter Commission in their nature or extent. Its proposals would virtually supplant the present system of taxation. Once they were adapted, the leading features of the present system would be scrapped, and there could be no return thereto without something of a convulsion in government and business. Nothing less than the most exhaustive study and understanding of the Commission's recommendations and their certain effects throughout Canada will do justice to the difficult and important decision with which the Commission has confronted the Government, Parliament and the Canadian people. In this confrontation those who will be responsible for taking farreaching decisions will need the assistance of all who by experience and study are capable of contributing to the elucidation of the implications of this report.

Parliament will require to devote long and patient study to the report. The minds of parliamentarians must be open to knowledgeable representations from every quarter. Hasty decisions could have calamitous consequences.

How should the individual citizen measure the value of the Commission's recommendations? Should he merely be guided by personal advantage? Perhaps it is natural for him to determine his attitude toward the report in terms of selfinterest. Perhaps I am merely naive in hoping that we may all be guided by larger considerations and a long-term view. With this hope I should couple a warning. The Commission has estimated that if its recommendations are fully carried into effect 46% of the people would pay less in taxes than at present. Perhaps the authors of the report were not completely unaware of the subtle popular appeal of such a prospect. Are we all to make our personal calculations in the hope that we may find ourselves among the lucky 46%. For my part I remain a little dubious as to such a precise estimate, and I point out both that the scales can change materially from year to year and that the alleged saving is in many cases not significant. It would be regrettable if the assumption by some taxpayers that they have a vested interest in the implementation of the report were to discourage or preclude them from making a thorough examination and evaluation of all its features.

In all these circumstances the principal responsibility will rest upon the government and in a paramount sense on the Minister of Finance. He and his colleagues after taking what time they need to make the most thorough study of the report and its implications must then be prepared to take their solemn responsibility for recommending courses of action. I hear it said that the government may choose to have a private member introduce the sort of bill that would be required to implement the recommendations in the report and leave the issue, at least in the first instance, in the hands of Parliament without any firm indication of government policy. I hope that the rumours are baseless. I can only say that such a course would be a complete abdication of government responsibility. In no area of public concern is the responsibility of the government to decide and recommend to Parliament firm legislative courses of action greater than in the fiscal field.

The public should understand what the introduction of a radically new system of taxation will involve. In the first place, the new system would initially present enormous problems in budgeting. Even with the most careful estimating, it would be extremely difficult to make precise estimates of the revenue yields from new and radically different taxes. Only with experience could the estimates hope to become as precise as revenue estimates ought to be for the purpose of the annual national budget. The Commission has come up with an estimate, based on the figures for the year 1964, that had its recommendations been in effect the total tax yield would have been $222,000,000 in excess of the yield from taxes in effect that year. I confess that I approach the Commission's precise figures in this respect with a measure of reserve.

The introduction of a radically new system of taxation will also cast enormous burdens upon those charged with administrative responsibility. It would involve casting away much of the expertise and experience gained by the staff of the Department of National Revenue in administering our existing taxes, whether personal income tax, corporation tax, sales tax, gift tax, estate tax, excise tax or other levies. To acquire the same degree of expertise in administering and enforcing a radically new system of taxation will require time and retraining on a very large scale.

5o far I have spoken only of the difficulties which would be faced by the government and the public service in introducing the radically new tax system. The problem presented to the taxpayer is equally formidable. To understand the new system of taxation and to be in a position to make correct decisions on it will present business men and their professional advisers with serious problems, many of which cannot be fully foreseen. Even today with a well-established system problems are constantly arising in actual experience. It should not be thought that the introduction of a radically new system will eliminate all uncertainty and solve all tax problems that arise in the experience of business unless, of course, one proceeds on the assumption that everything is to be taxed.

In brief, therefore, it seems to me that to allow for the government and its advisers to reach their conclusions and formulate their legislative proposals to Parliament, then for Parliament to study and debate such measures, then for the tax authorities and their staff to prepare for the introduction of the new system, and for business and other taxpayers to adjust themselves to the introduction of the new system, a very long time is likely to be required. This is most regrettable, for it means a prolongation of the period of uncertainty and indecision. Had the Commission's proposals been assimilable into the present system there would have been no occasion for such extended delay. It becomes inevitable, however, in my opinion, if the radical transformation of our tax system recommended by the Commission be put into effect in its entirety or nearly in its entirety. That the Commission has made no recommendations with respect to something that lies at the very heart of our tax problems may be regretted. I refer to the swelling volume of government expenditure. The Commission, however, has been quick to point out that they were not "asked to make recommendations with respect to the level or composition of federal government expenditures". The responsibility for grappling with this ever-present menace must remain with government, Parliament and the public. We shall continue to have tax problems of grievous proportions until there is a stronger determination to resist increases in expenditure. Every cent which governments spend must be raised from the public in some form. I would like to see a stiffening of the federal will to live within our means and to grapple with our tax problems at the true source.

I confess that I view not without alarm the Commission's estimate that its proposals, if introduced in their entirety, would in the year 1964 have yielded $222 million more in revenue than the taxes then in effect. To the federal spenders this is likely to prove one of the strongest inducements to adopt the Commission's recommendations. We should realize precisely what this means. In simple terms, had the Commission's recommendations been in effect three years ago the Canadian people, in the aggregate, would have been called upon to pay to the tax-gatherers $222 million more than they did. What this would mean in the year 1967 or in any other year we are not yet told.

The Commission severely indicts the present tax system. It does so in the form of seven clearly stated conclusions which in its opinion constitute what it calls "severe criticism" of the present system. These seven grounds are unquestionably formidable, even if some of them may be open to debate. The Commission concedes that "the present Canadian tax system is as good as most other systems" but it is "convinced that it falls short of the attainable objectives". For these reasons it recommends what it describes as "many fundamental changes which, if adopted, would produce a complete transformation . . .". I share the Commission's dislike for some of the features of the present tax system. I suspect that other Ministers of Finance may have felt likewise. The difficulty has been that the burden of fiscal responsibilities in the form of spending commitments has deprived them of freedom in eliminating or reducing inequities and unduly severe taxes. In my humble opinion the greatest fault in our present federal tax system is that the rates are so high. The second is that the tax sources are not distributed among the three levels of government with sufficient regard for the burdens which the provinces and municipalities are today required to bear. These two fundamental criticisms are not to be found among the seven set forth in the report.

The Commission holds forth equity as the guiding principle in devising its new system of taxation. The report calls for "both horizontal and vertical equity". No one can disagree with this objective. When the Commission states,

"The first and most essential purpose of taxation is to share the burden of the state fairly among all individuals and families."

I am certain that none will disagree. Difficulties commence, however, when this lofty principle is given practical application. I daresay that no Minister of Finance ever conceded that his proposals, however regrettable, were guided by any other consideration than equity and fairness. The area of agreement, however, rarely extends beyond the assertion of the principle.

Conceding the equity principle, what other considerations should guide those devising and applying a system of taxation? It is so common and so easy to say that taxation should be based upon the "ability to pay". This, however, is not an expression of exact meaning, and there is always room for difference as to what constitutes in even relative terms ability to pay.

Taxation should not discourage thrift. Taxation should not be allowed to discourage the fruitful development of our resources. Taxation ought not to numb incentive. Taxation should be as simple in nature and as clear in expression and intent as may be possible in a growing complex economy. Taxation should be stable and its application predictable. It should encourage tax consciousness. All of these are undoubtedly counsels of perfection, but they are among the sound principles which should guide those who devise tax policy.

In a dynamic society there will never be finality in the tax system. Economic and social changes will produce new pressures and unforeseen results. Even if the new system of taxation recommended by the Commission were immediately introduced, experience will tell us that finality would elude our grasp and that revisions would continue to be an annual responsibility of government and Parliament. Any assumption of finality in relation to the proposed new system is, in my opinion, untenable in the light of experience.

Capital Gains

The most radical recommendations in the report are those in favour of a tax on world-wide capital gains, legacies and gifts at progressive income tax rates, and the substitution of the family for the individual as the tax unit. I shall deal later with the tax on estates and gifts.

Taxes on capital gains, though levied for years in the United Kingdom and United States, have never been introduced in Canada. While I was Minister of Finance I always resisted proposals for such a tax, and I must say that I did not encounter strong pressure in favour thereof. I was of opinion that, whatever justification there may be for such a tax in countries with a capital surplus, like the United States and the United Kingdom, it was quite inappropriate to a capital-importing country like Canada. I genuinely feared that such a tax in Canada would discourage domestic thrift and investment as well as foreign capital, all of which Canada urgently needed. When such a tax was discussed it was always in terms of a special tax on certain defined kinds of capital gain, and always at a special flat rate, usually 25 %. It is a very different kind of tax which the Commission has proposed. Indeed, it is not a new tax at all, but the inclusion of net capital gains of every kind in the tax base to which the high progressive rates of income tax apply. Some considerations would apply to mitigate the rigors of the measure, but in essence it becomes a matter of widening the tax base, not a new kind of tax. The Commission has been guided by a pithily stated principle, "It is what you get, not how you get it, that should count for tax purposes". For my part I am not prepared to commit myself to any such all-pervasive principle.

I am all too well aware of the difficulties in the present law in separating income and capital gains. This border is being constantly fought over in the Tax Appeal Board and the courts. It has often been argued that a tax of 25% on capital gains would not be too great a price for relief from present uncertainties in that respect. I have never shared the view that the introduction of a tax on capital gains would have the effect of satisfying either the courts or the taxgatherers that gains are to be presumed to be of a capital nature. Now the Commission would end all this border warfare by submerging capital gains in the not very refreshing flood-waters of liability to income tax.

The Commission has agreed that the full taxation of capital gains under our present tax systems might be disastrous. It, therefore, proposes certain safeguards against the full weight of this new exaction: the taxation of property gains would not be retroactive; there would be a lifetime exemption of $25,000 on gains from the sale of houses and farms; income-averaging over a period of five years would be allowed; all losses would be deductible in computing income except those on houses and personal-use items; full credit would be allowed for taxes paid by Canadian corporations. But above all, the Commission proposes certain modifications in the progressive rates of taxation applicable to the various strata of income and a ceiling rate of 50%, as opposed to the present 80%. With these alleviations the Commission believes its proposals to be equitable, and asserts that not to tax capital gains would no longer be equitable. It cannot estimate the revenue effects of its proposal.

That inequities exist in the present tax system is undeniable. The tax rates on earned income are so high today that they throw into stark contrast the tax position of those enjoying capital gains.

For my part I would feel less disturbed by this farreaching proposal if 1 could share with complete confidence the Commission's assumption that the top rate of levy on personal income will not exceed 50%. The Commission has repeatedly stated this limit as though it were as final as the laws of the Medes and Persians. I fear that the same political considerations which led to the introduction and maintenance of the present 80% ceiling rate might inhibit the reduction of that ceiling to 50%. Even if the 50% ceiling were enacted who can say that succeeding governments may not lay impious hands upon it if the big spenders continue in control of national policy? How well we know to our cost that there is no permanence in tax rates!

The administrative problems created by taxing capital gains would, in my opinion, be even more formidable than the Commission considers. They would require annual tax returns to include information on all securities and real property owned, with particulars of all property gains and all deductible property losses. Fair market values must be established at the date of introduction of the tax for all property of all kinds then held. The task of establishing fair value for unincorporated businesses and private companies and real estate would be simply baffling in many cases. We have trouble enough in establishing equality in assessing real estate values for municipal tax purposes. The administrative burdens and woes thrown on the tax authorities would contrast with the prosperity of professional appraisers.

I confess that it troubles me to see the base of the income tax, with its high progressive rates, enlarged to a virtually universal extent. Such a proposal would wear the guise of equity only if it were the sole means of securing and maintaining a substantial reduction in the rate of personal income tax. It has, of course, been welcomed by the socialists. It could open the door to their old cherished idea of a capital levy.

On this area of the report I am very much impressed by the minority views of Mr. Grant and Mr. Beauvais. Canada needs capital. Does it make sense to penalize it?

Employment and Other Income

The Commission's zeal for an all-inclusive tax base and the rule of sheer logic has led it into some very doctrinaire proposals. Perhaps, having decided upon a tax on capital gains, the Commission felt that it must take a hard line against even very small non-cash benefits provided by employers in favour of their employees. Perhaps this also is the reason for the proposal to treat bed and board in the home as taxable income even to relatives. Such proposals may be correct in theory, but in not a few cases they appear to be unenforceable. A tax on benefits measured in very small amounts which would cost more to collect than it would yield can hardly be regarded as practicable.

Similarly, the Commission proposes to tax family allowances, old age pension benefits, unemployment insurance benefits, workmen's compensation and all other kinds of social assistance and relief. Old age security payments are already included in taxable income. To tax the others, however, would undoubtedly lead to demands for off-setting increases in the payments. Indeed, the Commission proposes that these payments should in all cases be reviewed to ensure that their inclusion in taxable income does not result in hardships. I can see no merit in taxing these payments just to make a tax system based on a comprehensive tax base logical to the last degree when it would mean simply taking money out of the pocket with one hand and putting it back with the other.

Expense Accounts

Much attention has been attracted by the proposals of the Commission concerning business entertainment bills and transportation costs on business trips, although it recognizes that the amounts involved are probably relatively small. The Commissioners are not the first persons who have wrestled with this problem. It is one that has disturbed Ministers of Finance for some time. Undoubtedly abuses are practised in this field by some taxpayers. The problem has been to find a means of dealing with the problem which will at the same time be fair and effective and enforceable. In the past rigid scales of allowances for these purposes have been rejected because of the injustices that such rigidity would impose. The Commission now proposes fixed flat dollar limits. They have completely accepted the idea of the rigid scale. I prefer the view of Mr. Beauvais. It seems to me that the Commission's proposal is so rigid as to be unrealistic and that it will result in injustices.

Estates--Gifts and Bequests

The Commission recommends the repeal of the Estate Tax and Gift Tax in their entirety. This is a bold and arresting proposal. In their place it recommends that gifts and bequests be treated as income in the hands of the recipient and be taxed as such at progressive rates. The major alleviation is that gifts and estates, regardless of size, passing to a spouse or dependent children would to totally exempt. In addition, there would be a $5,000 lifetime exemption on gifts outside this small family unit and a generous provision permitting income-averaging over a ten-year period, five years back and five years forward, with respect to both gifts and bequests. A gift outside the family unit will be deemed to be a disposition at fair market value. Therefore, accrued gains will be taxed to the donor and the fair market value will be taxed as income to the donee. The net result of all these changes would be a very heavy increase in taxes from these sources, rising from the present $140 million to $350 million annually.

This proposal involves a revolutionary departure from concepts hitherto prevailing in Canada. The individual has been the tax unit; now he will be replaced by the inner family. All concepts of estate planning are knocked topsyturvy. Where now the effort has been to avoid the tax consequences of successions, the tax advantage would lie with outright succession from husband to wife and dependent children. To treat all others, including self-supporting children and close relatives as strangers in relation to taxes on succession, and to tax all gifts and bequests outside the family unit as income at high progressive rates, will rudely shatter established concepts.

It is unthinkable that such a radical change would be introduced unless the provinces vacate the succession duty field, and the Commission recommends that they do so. How the provinces can be convinced to vacate and how Quebec in particular can be persuaded to surrender its tax control over succession remain to be seen. In my view the provinces hold the key to the fate of this radical proposal, and I am conditioned by experience to believe that they will not lightly surrender their rights.

It is regrettable that until the fate of this proposal is finally determined the greatest uncertainty will surround all measures of estate planning.

It is interesting that the Commission has made findings and pronouncements on two vexed questions: -

First, does the present weight of federal estate tax and provincial succession duty force sale of family businesses, particularly to non-residents? After an examination of the evidence the Commission finds that no clear conclusion can be drawn from it.

Second, should these taxes be reduced to discourage Canadians from transferring their residence abroad to reduce the tax on their estates? The Commission answers with a firm and resounding "NO".

Corporations

One of the most interesting and attractive proposals relates to the taxation of corporations. The Commission would enlarge the tax base of corporations by including property gains, gifts, windfalls, etc. while at the same time allowing more generous deductions, such as payments for goodwill and the cost of obtaining certain types of contracts and lists of customers and the cost of issuing securities. To this enlarged base the Commission would apply the present 50% tax rate, eliminating altogether the prevailing reduction to 21 % on the first $35,000 of taxable income. To compensate for this deprivation it would institute a new kind of rapid depreciation allowances designed to assist new and small businesses for a period of ten years. The more generous provisions for carry-forward and carry-back of business losses, and concessions to all qualified businesses, whether or not incorporated, in relation to capital cost allowances will be warmly welcomed.

The most striking proposal, however, concerns integration of the corporation tax with taxes payable by shareholders. For tax purposes the taxable income of the corporation, whether distributed or not, would be deemed to be allocated among the shareholders. Each shareholder would then be given credit for his portion of the tax paid by the corporation and would offset it against his own tax. His tax base would be enlarged by this individual accrual, but except in the case of shareholders paying a personal tax rate of 50% or more, he would receive a tax credit. In effect the individual shareholder's proportion of the corporation's taxable income would be taxed at his personal rate, and there would be no double taxation of income earned by the corporation. The integration scheme would apply only in favour of Canadianresident shareholders. This proposal in its general features will undoubtedly.attract wide support.

It must be pointed out, that while the position of the shareholder as such is likely to be materially benefited, the position of the bondholder as such has in most cases been ignored. Unless some comparable concession can be extended to him the Commission's proposals are likely to distort debt financing by corporations.

Banks

In its zeal for simplifying general rules of taxation, the Commission has made specific proposals which will impose serious burdens upon our extractive industries, life insurance companies and banks and some other financial institutions. The proposals for reducing the tax-exempt inner reserves of the chartered banks are too large and involved a subject to be introduced in this address. But I must comment on the other two.

Mines and Petroleum Industries

The Commission recommends the immediate cancellation of the mining and petroleum depletion allowances and a phased withdrawal of the three-year tax exemption for new mines. These special concessions have been accorded by our income tax legislation for many years. They are a recognition of the wasting character of these assets of the extractive industries, and of the risks taken by investors and developers of mineral and petroleum deposits. They have played a very influential role in attracting investment, from both residents and non-residents, for the fruitful development of these natural resources, and their withdrawal will undoubtedly be widely publicized and will be interpreted as a loss of interest in the development of our resources. The Commission's proposals will cost these enterprises $136 million per annum, with most of the burden falling on the mines. These proposals are far too drastic, and I personally would firmly oppose them.

Life Insurance

Generally speaking, touay mutual life insurance companies are exempt from federal taxation, and joint stock companies pay a total of only $2 million. Since 1956 Parliament has largely left this industry to be taxed by the provinces, which have levied a premium tax yielding them about $15 million per annum. The Commission appears to suggest that the provinces should give up this revenue. It makes the radical proposal that all life insurance companies, whether resident or foreign, and whether organized as joint stock or mutual companies or as fraternal benefit societies, should be taxed in the same way as other corporations. The federal tax yield would rise from $2 million to $77 million per annum on the basis of the 1964 figures. The Commission acknowledges that there would be less money available for policy reserves, that there could be some reduction in policyholders' dividends, that premiums on policies issued in future would increase, and that life insurance as a form of savings could become relatively less attractive.

I must observe that the life insurance industry has enjoyed favoured federal tax treatment for a very good reason -that it is the soundest kind of social security, and that people should be encouraged to provide for themselves and their families by this means. The Commission admits making an exception on "social security" grounds in the case of . benefits gradually built up by contributions to pension retirement savings and profits. I cannot follow the logic of denying similar tax treatment to life insurance policies. Life insurance attracts 30% of total personal savings of Canadians. It channels those savings beneficially into mortgages, bonds, stocks and buildings. In 1966 the Canadian life companies paid out a billion dollars in benefits, two-thirds to living policyholders and one-third in death benefits. Canadians hold more life insurance per capita than the people of any other country. In proposing that all life insurance companies be taxed like any other industry the Commission has subordinated some very important considerations to a doctrinaire attachment to a dogma. For my part I am firmly opposed to their drastic proposal.

Charities

The Commission proposes that charities be taxed on their business income and some of their investment income. I recognize that the present rules in our tax legislation with respect to charities may not be perfect, but in principle I am opposed to taxing charities. For my part I could not accept the view of the Commission on this subject.

Sales Tax

The Commission has offered some interesting, but by no means novel, proposals respecting the sales tax. Under the constitution Parliament can raise money by any mode or system of taxation; the provinces are limited to direct taxes. The present federal sales tax is a classic example of an indirect tax. It is levied on the manufacturer or producer. He includes it in the price he charges to the wholesaler. The latter, in turn, includes it in the price he charges to the jobber or retailer. The latter in his turn includes it in the price he charges to the consumer. In every case mark-ups are added on the total price, and while the yield to the government from the tax is confined to the percentage paid by the manufacturer or producer, by the time the goods have reached the consumer several pyramided percentage markups on the tax are included in the end price. The tax is objectionable from several points of view. In the first place, it is hidden. The taxpayer, namely the consumer, is not aware of the amount of the tax he is actually paying. It costs the taxpayer much more than it yields to the government. Many people also object to it because, not only is it not a progressive tax, but in some respects it is regressive; that is to say, it bears no relation to the income or capital wealth of the taxpayer, but is based upon his consumption, which often must be identified with need.

From the government's point of view, however, the federal sales tax has the irresistible virtue that it is the easiest of all taxes to collect. It consists of a simple percentage, and it is levied at a level where it can be most easily collected. It can be raised or lowered with ease, for only a change in the flat percentage is involved. It produces a handsome yield. The sales tax imposed by nine of the provinces (Alberta only excepted) is of a different character. Being a provincial tax, it must be a direct tax. It must not be levied on anyone who will pass the tax on to someone else. Therefore, the tax must be imposed upon the consumer. It cannot even be constitutionally imposed upon the retailer. Therefore, the cumbersome method adopted to meet the problem is to levy the tax on the consumer and to constitute the retailer the government's agent for the purpose of collecting and remitting the tax on behalf of the taxpayer, namely, the consumer. Recently the federal sales tax was advanced to 12%, and three years ago exemptions in favour of building materials and production equipment were withdrawn. These measures have increased popular resistance to the federal sales tax.

The Commission recommends the abolition of the present federal sales tax in its entirety. In its place, however, with some sacrifice of revenue, it proposes a 7 % sales tax to be applied at the retail level to both consumer goods and services. The inclusion of services will greatly widen the tax base, although there are some notable exemptions, for example, raw materials, unfinished goods, production equipment and machinery, goods for export, finished buildings and structures and capital goods used in distribution and services. The proposal to restore the former exemption in favour of production equipment has been welcomed. The Commission also recommends the eventual removal of the sales tax on building materials and this proposal has likewise been warmly received.

The Commission proposes an amendment to the constitution to permit the provinces to levy an indirect sales tax on the retailer, and that where a province has a general sales tax rate of 5% with the same tax base as the proposed federal tax, the provincial governments might undertake the collection of the combined 12% for both governments. As against very great administrative problems which would arise from the change in the level at which the federal tax is imposed, and a sacrifice of $175 million of federal revenue, the proposal to combine the collection of the two taxes offers advantages. The collection at the retail level will assure that the customer is made well aware of the tax he is paying. Moreover, there will be no mark-up on the tax. The adoption of the direct tax at the retail level, however, will give rise to great difficulties in enforcement, and I expect it will be strongly resisted by the federal tax authorities. Sales at the consumer level being far more numerous than those at the manufacturers' or producers' level, the adoption of the indirect retail tax will necessitate enforcement through a multitude of retailers. The problems of enforcement would be greatly multiplied as compared with the present federal tax.

It should be realized that the inclusion of services in the tax base will widen considerably the incidence and irritations of the federal sales tax. The removal of the tax at the manu facturers' or producers' level ought to result in a reduction of prices at that level. Can anyone guarantee that it will?

Provinces and Municipalities

While its terms of reference made no express mention of federal-provincial fiscal relations, the Commission decided that it was not precluded from examining their effect on the Canadian fiscal system. They, therefore, took account of what they believed to be the objectives in that field and undertook to develop a tax structure consistent with the realization thereof. They refrained from considering the division of tax revenue between federal and provincial governments. Their recommendations offer no tangible relief for either provincial or municipal governments in the fiscal strait-jacket in which they unhappily find themselves.

Briefly, the report opposes any further abatement of the personal and corporation income taxes in favour of the provinces. It looks upon the personal income tax as the federal government's most effective tool for stabilizing the economy. It recommends that the provinces abolish succession duties. It suggests that if Ottawa wishes to give the provinces more tax room it do so by reducing its own rate of sales tax, presumably to allow the provinces to increase theirs beyond the proposed 5%. It notes the necessity for adoption of a uniform income tax base by both federal and provincial governments and hopes that the broad new base it would propose will be as attractive to the provinces as to the federal government.

It appears to me that this report offers but cold comfort to the provinces and municipalities in their genuine fiscal anxieties. For my part I am concerned that in today's cir cumstances the Commission has leaned so heavily in favour of the federal level of government.

Administration

Tax administration is a subject of very considerable importance under any circumstances. The commission has recommended a completely new system of Canadian tax administration. It proposes that the functions of the Department of National Revenue be assumed by an independent board of revenue commissioners, reporting directly to Parliament through the Minister of Finance and having somewhat the same relationship to the government as has the Bank of Canada. The Commission also proposes that a new tax board be established to replace the existing Tax Appeal Board and possibly also the judicial functions of the Tariff Board.

The Commission expresses the opinion that by placing tax collection under the proposed new board "impartiality would be assured and any attempt to exert political influence on the collecting authority would be negated". This assertion standing alone would have seemed to suggest that the Commission had found evidence that political considerations were influencing decisions of the Department of National Revenue. If so, knowing the highly competent men who have served the public in the Department of National Revenue, I would have resented it. However, the Commission has emphasized that it is not implying that it has found any disturbing shortcomings in the Department of National Revenue but, on the contrary, that the officials of that Department are "carrying out their duties in a dedicated and conscientious way".

The Commission thinks it is sufficient that responsibility for actual tax policy remain with the government and particularly the Minister of Finance, but that administration can be severed entirely from political responsibility. This is a new doctrine, and in my judgment, an unrealistic one. Administration is a government responsibility. Attempts in the past to separate areas of the public service from the principle of governmental responsibility have created frequent border wars. The public has never yet accepted the idea that there are, or can be, areas of the public service and public enterprise that lie totally outside the realm of government responsibility. What the public demands are governments not with reduced areas of responsibility, but with a higher sense of responsibility.

The Minister of Finance charged with responsibility for tax policy needs the full and intimate assistance of the senior officers of the Department of National Revenue. Relations between the Minister of Finance and an independent board, holding itself responsible only to Parliament and not to government, would be very different, and would, I fear, deny to the Minister of Finance assistance of a kind which he often needs. '

Any proposal for improving and expediting appeals and improving the machinery for tax settlements should be very sympathetically considered.

Simplification of Forms and Procedures

I am sure that many good people had hoped that it would be possible for the Commission to simplify tax forms, tax procedures and tax legislation. The Commission admits that is can hold out no such hope. Even with the virtually allinclusive new proposed tax base, the Commission has concluded that tax forms are likely to be more complex than in the past. This will be very disappointing news.

Foreign Capital

I am very pleased that the Commission has expressed its firm opposition to anything which would create the impression that Canada is hostile to foreign investment. On the other hand, it desires that foreign subsidiaries in Canada become more conscious of the Canadian public interest. With this aim I am sure that most of us are in complete agreement. Fiscal measures should not be called upon unduly to sustain government policy in other fields, and we must be on our guard against radical changes of the rules under which foreign investment has been attracted to Canada. We have seen the disastrous effects of punitive applications of fiscal discrimination against foreign investment.

The Commission concluded that Canada's rate of saving is high and it found "no great merit" in providing tax incentives to raise it still further as a means of reducing reliance on foreign capital. It saw no reason to favour personal saving any more than corporate saving or a government surplus. The Commission disclaims any belief that the adoption of its proposals will have a dramatic effect on foreign ownership and control. I should think that on balance they will have a discouraging effect on future foreign investment.

Balance of Payments

It is evident that the Commission has not considered that our tax system should bear major responsibility for solving Canada's chronic balance of payments problem. It has not, however, overlooked the effect of its proposals on that problem. Its proposals on balance might reduce slightly our balance of payments deficit, and this will be accounted in their favour. Stabilization Policies

The use of fiscal measures for the purpose of regulating the economy is too large a subject to be discussed adequately today. The Commission urges faster and more effective federal action to prevent or check inflations and recessions. This is a laudable goal. The means proposed by the Commission, however, will probably win less unanimous support. The Commission proposes that when either the employment rate or price increases exceed previously defined limits a full-scale debate in the House of Commons should be mandatory and that the government should be required to state what it is doing and what it intends to do about the situation. This is a beautiful theory, but it appears to assume that government can be reformed just like the tax system.

The Commission also proposes that the government should have standby authority to change specific taxes within defined limits subject to later parliamentary approval. There is, of course, a precedent for this proposal in legislation passed several years ago in the United Kingdom. In terms of constitutional usage, this is a radical proposal. It is a soundly established principle since the days of Charles II that taxes can be imposed only by Parliament, and Parliament has been unwilling to legislate to confer upon government power to vary taxes, particularly power to increase them. We have some exceptions in our tariff legislation, but none of consequence with respect to the principal forms of taxation. I doubt if the Canadian Parliament will be disposed to vest very wide powers of this kind in Ministers.

Severability

I referred at the outset to the Commission's claim that its proposals should be accepted in their entirety as a package, an integrated programme. On analysis it seems to me that certain of their major proposals do fall in that category: the inclusion of capital gains, gifts and legacies in taxable income subject to progressive tax rates; and the substitution of the inner family as the tax unit. Other important proposals are, in my opinion, severable and can be considered on their individual merits. Such are the retail sales tax, the taxation of life insurance companies, banks, the petroleum and mining industries, charities, expense accounts, etc. Parliament should not be denied its right to consider the individual parts as well as the whole of the proposed new tax system. Moreover, nearly all of the proposals are open to modification in one form or another, as the minority reports recommend in a number of cases.

Conclusion

Perhaps you will concede that our President assigned me a large and intolerably long task. At the outset I stressed that my theme is limited to "Some Thoughts on the Carter Report". I said that at this early stage and in one address I could not hope to offer more than a preliminary review and assessment of the report, confined to some broad considerations and certain of its highlights. I hope that my observations will encourage you to study for yourselves this very valuable, stimulating, challenging and most controversial report. Its importance justifies our attentive study; its contents will fully repay it.

Thanks of the meeting were expressed Mr. Sydney Hermant.

Powered by / Alimenté par VITA Toolkit
Privacy Policy